Latest news about Bitcoin and all cryptocurrencies. Your daily crypto news habit.
Itâs a basic principle of human behavior that people are more cooperative when eyes are watching. I mean this literally and figuratively. Literally because you donât need a human to watch, just eyes. And figuratively because these eyes donât even need to be real, they can just be an illustrated pair of eyes. Iâm not kidding. A famous social-psychological study[1] showed that people are less likely to free-ride a supposed honor system based coffee stand when a sign asking them to leave money in a cup had a pair of eyes drawn on it. Actually, people left nearly three times more money than they did when the picture was just of flowers. As Daniel Kahneman, one of the founding fathers of behavioral economics puts it, people are âendlessly complicated and interesting.â[2]
Of course, the general principle that humans cooperate more when other people are watching (called âreputation managementâ by the likes of psychologists and game theorists), is just plain common sense. The hard part isnât identifying this tendency, the hard part is figuring out how to make people cooperate when no one is looking (and when drawing a pair of eyes on paper just doesnât cut it). We struggle with this in the physical world. Consider the predicament limited natural resources present. Itâs hard to turn your AC down in the summertime if you think that your doing so will cause you to suffer, and your neighbors wonât turn their AC down so it doesnât make a difference anyway. âAh, what the heck, Iâll just keep it at 72â is closely followed by nasty, preventable blackouts. Such is the tragedy of the commons.
Many people believe it is the job of the government to regulate and fairly allocate such common resources. Without Californiaâs water conservation laws, people would fare much worse in the drought, the argument goes. We canât trust people to be selfless, so we need Uncle Sam, and his very foreboding eyes, to come and babysit.
Letâs consider what the commons dilemmas have looked like in the cyber world. Storage, bandwidth, and computation are the three basic infrastructural needs of the electronic universe. And rather than entering into a social contract with Uncle Sam directly, cyber citizens have entered into social contracts (otherwise known as Terms of Service) with the Big Four. It goes something like this: We will provide you with reliable storage, bandwidth, and computation and in return, youâll let us mine your data and metadata for profit.
Users agree, and voila: Google, Amazon, Facebook, and Apple traffic-direct their limited, albeit large, resources as they please. In exchange the Big Four mine and profit off user-generated data. And all people of the world live happily ever after cyber lives. Until Uncle Sam pulls the plug on net neutrality and they realize that nobody watches the watchmenâââexcept for friends of lobbyistsâââwhich isnât all that reassuring.
âWho watches the watchmen?â: Crypto-economic platforms
This sentiment rings popular with Crypto-Libertarians and Classical Liberals, but it leaves many concerned that the Wild West of Initial Coin Offerings are just dirty scams to make a quick buck. So, whatâs with these ICOs anyhow?
Cryptocurrencies now are being crafted and tailored to meet specific cyber resource needs. Filecoin uses coins as cooperation incentives for a Dropbox-like decentralized storage system. Ethereum uses coins for decentralized computational power. AXE* uses coins as cooperation incentives for decentralized bandwidth. Are you seeing the theme? The heart of the crypto crowd is to replace biased, and sometimes downright unethical, governing third-parties with unwavering algorithms and ledgers that every peer gets to watch. Everyone is a watchman. Ancient Greeceâs vision for democracy realized in the electronic economic realm.
But what makes this any different than crypto-anarchism? Shortly after Bitcoin started to picking up traction and being used by the infamous Silk Road, much of the general public began to equate cryptocurrencies with shady business deals. Bitcoin isnât regulated, so obviously the purpose of Bitcoin is to empower pimps and drug-rings, the thought went. But, itâs not entirely true that Bitcoin isnât regulated. It isâââitâs just crowd-sourced regulation. And this might be a primordial goo we social psychologists can work with.
The four âIâs
Social psychologist Mark Van Vugt[3] has outlined the four âIâs that motivate successful resolution of commons dilemmas: Identity, institutions, incentives, and information. So letâs take a look at what these new crypto-era cipher startups will need to pull off.
Identity.
Although many equate cryptocurrencies with privacy, remember that they are all based on public ledgers. Itâs more confidential than anonymous per-se. Each action is added to a record associated with a public key. While you might not know that Jane Smith ripped 5 people in a row off, you do know that X public key ripped 5 people in a row off, was nice to two people before that, and free-rode prior to that. Probably best not to take your chances doing business with X public key.
This is more powerful than you might initially imagine. Psychologists have found that people are far from fair in their interactions in totally anonymous so-called âdictator games.â In these games, an individual is put in a seat of total power (the dictator) to split valued resources between themselves and another party. Unsurprisingly, when the dictator has the benefit of anonymity, they tend to hoard the resources. However, if the rules of the game are shifted such that the dictator role swaps between parties in subsequent rounds, and the players of the game can keep a mental record of one anotherâs dictatorship roles over time, people become much more friendly. This behavioral change is unsurprising, but keep in mind that this happens even though no oneâs private identity is revealed. Give me a public ledger, and Iâll show you a (probabilistically) honest man.
But, take the mask off and the effects are all the more powerful. If you can connect actions with a personâs true face and name, behaviors become increasingly prosocial.[4] Twitterâs blue check mark is aimed at reliably verifying identities to prevent bad actors from impersonating. But on second glance, it also keeps the real Slim Shady from being, well, shady. Martti âSiriusâ Malmi, the first developer of Bitcoin after Satoshi, is working to create one such decentralized identity system, called Identifi. Potential gossip is a powerful motivator. Show me a face and a name, and Iâll show you either an honest person, or a non-rational masochist.
Institutions.
Hereâs where I abstractly disagree Van Vugt. He says that institutions are needed to build trust between individuals in commons exchanges. Cryptoeconomic exchanges operate orthongonally to this principle. Rather than attempting to create trust, they simply do-away with it. They create âtrust-lessâ systems. Trust is automated in this frontier. Itâs not something you pay for, itâs something you take for granted.
So, letâs instead take a liberal interpretation of Van Vugt and say that âalgorithmsâ can substitute for âinstitutionsâ in the cipher world. Bitcoin makes the trustworthiness of a purchaser irrelevant. The algorithm simply ensures no double-spending will occur, adds the exchange to the blockchain ledger, and all eyes everywhere bear witness to that interaction. The elegance of blockchain-based cryptoeconomic platforms is that they eliminate the need for trusted institutional mediators.
Incentives.
Humans seek pleasure and avoid pain. This is a no-brainer, and it hasnât escaped the likes of Bitcoin, AXE, Filecoin, and Ethereum. These platforms have built incentives into the softwareâs infrastructure, and done so craftily to get around the chicken-and-egg problems that plague new currencies. Bitcoinâs mining system, for instance, releases fewer coins with each new block. This incentivizes early adoption by eliminating long-term inflation, and makes coins mined early on more valuable when considering the proof-of-work required to mine them.
AXE has innovated upon this idea with its two-dimensional blockchain. As coins are exchanged for decentralized bandwidth, the coins collect a sort of wear-and-tear. Thus the earliest adopters who âhodlâ genesis coins will have the most valuable coins in the entire system. But mining restores some of the life into a used coin, akin to a used laptop regaining some of itâs value by becoming refurbished. This wear-and-tear function prevents Sybil attacks, because artificial exchanges aimed at inflating oneâs reputation would result in wear-and-tear on the transfer coins, which ultimately punishes the schemer. This is an example of how cryptoeconomic platforms can add punishments over and above poor reputations.
Information.
Humans crave information. We just donât like being the dark. We need to feel competent that our cooperative actions (or inactions) in a common system will actually make a difference. These crypto-coin companies will need to educate their users in how bad-acting will affect the overall ecosystem, and how good-acting will make a measurable difference as well. This goes for personal rewards and punishments and reputation management too. In case anyone offering coins is listening: this crypto-decentralized stuff isnât intuitive, make sure users know the basic cause-and-effects of your systems.
Psychologists are cynical about human nature. Itâs why we put people into dictator games and document their dark sides emerging. I earned my doctorate specializing in the study of human morality. Based on my experience, cryptoeconomic platforms should aim to disseminate information which elicits âelevationâ (a sense of awe and wonder at the moral beauty) of cryptographic decentralized platforms.
People also need information about why they ought to care about cryptoeconomic platforms. If these big ICO projects wish to cut down on free-riders, they need to make their philanthropic message clearer. By being honest in these cryptoeconomic platforms, users are empowering marginalized individuals to access private data storage, computation, and information transfer. The point of crypto-this, crypto-that decentralized everything isnât to buy drugs, and itâs not really to avoid international transfer fees or even so much to retain privacy. These are side-effects.
Itâs to say âdown with the tyrants.â Itâs to drive the marginal costs of information to near-zero, so that any one in the world can become educated. Itâs to prevent censorship. Itâs to allow women to have bank accounts. Itâs to keep corrupt governments from making lifetime-savings transactions mysteriously disappear. Itâs to break telecommunications monopolies. Itâs to level the playing field. Itâs to disrupt racism, sexism, classism. Itâs to jump out of the gunky matrix that lobbyists and politicians have plugged us into. Do you want to cheat and free-ride that system? Do you want to destroy that vision? Iâm guessing you donât.
*The author is an employee of AXEâs parent company.
[1]Bateson, M., Nettle, D., & Roberts, G. (2006). Cues of being watched enhance cooperation in a real-world setting. Biology Letters, 2(3), 412â414.
[2]Nobel Prize Autobiographical Information; https://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2002/kahneman-bio.html
[3]Van Vugt, M. (2009). Averting the tragedy of the commons: Using social psychological science to protect the environment. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 18(3), 169â173.
[4]Piazza, J., & Bering, J. M. (2008). Concerns about reputation via gossip promote generous allocations in an economic game. Evolution and Human Behavior, 29(3), 172â178.
Game of Coins: The Behavioral Economics of Crypto was originally published in Hacker Noon on Medium, where people are continuing the conversation by highlighting and responding to this story.
Disclaimer
The views and opinions expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not reflect the views of Bitcoin Insider. Every investment and trading move involves risk - this is especially true for cryptocurrencies given their volatility. We strongly advise our readers to conduct their own research when making a decision.